Tax Simplification: Just Get
Rid of 89 Million Unnecessary Returns
by Jay Starkman, CPA
"
The individual income tax is our fiscal beast of burden."
IRS statistics reveal that just 9 percent of individual income tax revenue is raised from 68
percent of the returns filed with the IRS -- 89 million of the 130 million returns processed
. That means that an inordinate amount of resources are devoted to collecting $72 billion of
tax. The remaining 32 percent of the tax returns yield $725 billion. The 68 percent includes
all single persons earning up to a little over
$35,000 annually and all married couples earning up to a little over $60,000.
Table
1. 2002 IRS Statistics of Income Summary Estimate of Taxes
Raised
by Incomes Not Exceeding the 15 Percent
Tax Bracket (tax dollars in thousands)
|
Single
|
Married
Joint
|
Head
of Household
and Other
|
Total
|
Gross
income taxed at 15 percent or less |
$35,650 |
$60,550 |
$47,350 |
|
Tax
collections for taxpayers not exceeding the 15 percent bracket* |
$37,195,692 |
$23,812,874 |
$11,455,869 |
$72,464,435 |
Total
Tax collections, all incomes
|
$184,587,392
|
$565,077,480 |
$47,321,396 |
$796,986,268 |
Percentage
of total tax collections, from those in 15 percent bracket or less
|
20%
|
4%
|
24%
|
9%
|
Number of
Returns, for taxpayers not exceeding the 15 percent bracket
|
Nontaxable
|
15,108,925 |
9,623,006
|
12,368,747 |
37,100,678 |
Taxable
|
28,090,616 |
17,527,845 |
6,205,858 |
51,824,319 |
Total
|
43,199,541 |
27,150,851 |
18,574,605 |
88,924,997 |
Total
Returns, all incomes
|
57,199,788 |
51,302,090 |
18,574,605 |
130,076,444 |
Percentage of
returns up to the 15 percent bracket
|
76% |
53% |
86% |
68% |
Source:
Author's
calculations based on data from IRS Statistics of Income 2002 (Winter
2005), "Table 1.2 -- 2002, Individual
Income Tax, All Returns: Adjusted Gross Income, Exemptions, Deductions,
and Tax Items, by Size of Adjusted Gross Income and by Marital Status."
The author claims no expertise in the black art of revenue estimating.
With more
detailed statistics these estimates, especially the married-joint
calculation, could be better delineated. For purposes of this article,
the
estimates are presented as reasonable evidence to bolster the
contention that the vast majority of income tax returns raise little
revenue. |
* Income
only for those whose adjusted gross income is less than
$35,600/$47,350/$60,550 is
considered. That is the total of taxable income comprising the 15
percent
bracket plus the standard deduction and personal exemption. Income from
capital gains above those amounts, which is taxed at 15 percent,
is excluded. Dependent exemptions are excluded. These taxes reflect
$1.1 billion of EITC that is included in the IRS statistics to the
extent that its application does not reduce income tax before
credits below zero. Child credits are included to the same extent,
but the amount of credit cannot be determined. |
The last time the United States really simplified the income tax
was in 1872, when the Civil War income tax was repealed. Every tax act
since has added complexity. Laws purporting to simplify include new
elections, computations, deductions, credits, or phase-ins. Targeted
simplification, like simplifying the definition of dependent or the
proposed rationalization of the myriad education incentives, merely mop
up the mess created by prior tax bills, clearing the deck for future
complications.
Recently, there have been two articles proposing real
simplification: "100 Million Unnecessary Returns" by Michael Graetz
(Yale University)
2 and "44 Million Will File Tax Returns But
Pay Nothing" by Scott Hodge (the Tax Foundation).
3 The IRS
receives 130 million Forms 1040 annually. True simplification would
reduce tax filings by tens of millions.
Does fairness require that everyone participate in the income tax
for the upkeep of government? Even when compliance costs make it
uneconomical? How did the income tax become a tax on the masses?
My objectives in this article are to explain the historical reasons
that we have no national sales tax and how that contributed to income
tax complexity, and to show that real simplification requires exempting
a majority of the population from the income tax.
How Income Tax Became a Mass Tax
Initially, the income tax was strictly a revenue measure. Once the
Civil War debt was repaid, that revenue was no longer needed, so the
1862-1872 income tax was repealed. For the next 40 years, the
government was financed through excises and high tariffs -- consumption
taxes.
The poor spent every penny, so they bore a heavy burden of
consumption taxes. The wealthy, to the extent they saved or spent funds
on services or nonimports, paid a lighter tax as a percentage of
income. That made taxation regressive. Adding some progressivity to the
nation's tax system was the impetus behind the 1894 income tax. It was
a 2 percent tax on incomes exceeding $4,000.
Congress debated whether income tax should be used for
progressivity or whether everyone should participate. Rep. William
Bourke Cockran of New York, reputed to be the best Democratic orator in
the House, made a convincing argument against an income tax targeting
only the rich:
You have not attempted to tax the people, but you have attempted to tax
the incomes of 85,000 of them. You have undertaken to set aside a class
on which alone this tax is to fall, and to degrade the balance of the
people to a plane of inferior importance. . . . He who is relieved from
taxation, who is exempt from his share in one single burden of
government, forfeits to that extent the grounds upon which his right to
control the Government is based.4
Rep. William Jennings Bryan retorted eloquently:
Why, sir, the gentleman from New York said that the poor are opposed to
this tax because they do not want to be deprived of participation in
it, and that taxation instead of being a sign of servitude is a badge
of freedom. If taxation is a badge of freedom, let me assure my friend
that the poor people of this country are covered all over with the
insignia of freemen.5
The 1894 tax passed, but was soon declared unconstitutional. Following
ratification of the 16th Amendment, the 1913 income tax had the same
goal, featuring a $3,000 ($4,000 married) exemption with graduated
rates from 1 percent to 7 percent to enhance progressivity. To finance
World War I, rates rose all the way to 77 percent, but the exemption
remained high enough to exempt most of the population. See Table 2.
In a misguided attempt to balance the budget in 1932, House Speaker
John Nance Garner reached agreement with Treasury Secretary Ogden Mills
and Ways and Means Committee Chair Charles Crisp to support a 2.25
percent national sales tax on everything except food and cheaper
clothing. Almost every national political leader from the president to
the leaders of both houses of Congress supported the sales tax. So did
Bernard Baruch and William Randolph Hearst. To disguise the nature of
the tax, it would be called a "manufacturer's tax."
Led by Reps. Fiorello LaGuardia, who later became mayor of New York
City, and Robert Doughton, who later became chair of the Ways and Means
Committee, members rebelled against their House leaders. The tax was
opposed by the American Federation of Labor, four farm groups,
retailers, and wholesalers. There were mass meetings throughout the
country to protest the tax. It was overwhelmingly defeated.
There was a general feeling that sales tax was the domain of the
states, and that the federal government should not endeavor to enact a
sales tax because it would compete with the states' ability to raise
revenue. To cover the revenue shortfall, the Revenue Act of 1932
boosted income tax and estate tax rates.
In a lame duck session in December 1932, President Herbert Hoover
again asked Congress to enact the sales tax and Garner promised to
allow the bill to reach the House floor. Thereupon, President-elect
Franklin Delano Roosevelt announced that he opposed a federal sales
tax. From his experience as New York's governor, Roosevelt decided it
was best that federal and state governments not levy taxes on the same
source and that a general sales tax should be the exclusive domain of
the states. The federal sales tax proposal was dead.
6
World War II brought not only high rates but decreases in the
personal exemption. Wage withholding was introduced to avoid a
collection nightmare. The income tax was transformed from an elite tax
to a mass tax. Why?
The personal exemption was significantly lowered in 1940 and again
in 1941 as part of a "preparedness" campaign. The Roosevelt
administration in 1942 contemplated financing for World War II through
higher income tax rates. Republicans proposed an alternative: A sales
tax for the purpose of having those with low incomes contribute to the
treasury. Had Roosevelt not opposed a federal sales tax, we would have
one today. Instead, Treasury Secretary Henry Morgenthau made a
counterproposal to lower the personal exemption to $624. It was
uneconomical to have income tax reach such small incomes, but it was
sold as a compromise to defeat the sales tax initiative.
7
Table 2. Personal Exemption 1913-1969
Exemption |
Single
|
Married
|
Dependents
|
1913-1916
|
$3,000
|
$4,000
|
$-0-
|
1917-1920
|
$1,000
|
$2,000
|
$200
|
1921-1924
|
$1,000 |
$2,500 |
$400
|
1925-1931
|
$1,500 |
$3,500 |
$400 |
1932-1939
|
$1,000 |
$2,500 |
$400 |
1940
|
$800
|
$2,000 |
$400 |
1941
|
$750 |
$1,500 |
$400 |
1942-1943
|
$624 |
$1,248 |
$312 |
1944-1947
|
$500 |
$1,000 |
$500 |
1948-1969
|
$600 |
$1,200 |
$600 |
Source:
IRS Statistics of Income, Appendix to Selected Historical and Other
Data Tables, Table A. --
U.S. Individual Income Tax: Personal Exemptions and and Highest
Brackets Tax Rates, and Tax Base for Regular Tax, Tax Years
1913-2003 (except 1942-1943 taken from Randolph Paul, Taxation in
the United States (Boston: Little, Brown, and Company, 1954), p.
348). See http://www.irs.gov/pub/irs-soi/03inta.xls
. |
The personal exemption reached a nadir of $500 in 1944, but that was
enacted in conjunction with a new standard deduction and with an
increase in the dependent exemption. Those 1944 changes dropped 12
million low-income people from the tax rolls. The Roosevelt
administration recognized that collecting $161 million from taxpayers
near the bottom endangered collection of $17 billion from 50 million
other taxpayers.
8
President Harry Truman cited fear of inflation and later
financing for the Korean War as reasons for not lowering rates or
raising exemptions. There was some modest relief in 1947, when rates
were lowered slightly and the personal exemption was raised to $600.
President Dwight Eisenhower made overhaul of the Internal
Revenue Code in 1954 the centerpiece of his tax policy. Its major
individual tax policy was recodification of the World War II tax
policy, making low-income individuals liable for income tax. Eisenhower
echoed 19th century philosophy when he threatened to veto any bill that
included an increase in exemptions, declaring:
When the time comes to cut income taxes still more, let's cut them. But
I do not believe that the way to do it is to excuse millions of
taxpayers from paying any income tax at all . . . every real American
is proud to carry his share of any burden. . . . I simply do not
believe for one second that anyone privileged to live in this country
wants someone else to pay his fair and just share of the cost of his
Government.9
Complexity as Tax Relief
Alternate methods were created to supplement the personal exemption.
The standard deduction, introduced as a 10 percent deduction ($1,000
maximum) from adjusted gross income in 1944, was converted into a fixed
deduction after 1976. The refundable earned income tax credit is
essentially a subsidy on the minimum wage. The child tax credit is a
proxy for an increased dependent exemption and partial relief from
FICA/Self-Employment tax.
The exemptions and standard deduction excused about half of all
families from tax after World War II. Inflation, rising real incomes,
bracket creep, and failure to adequately increase the exemption have
now made the income tax almost universal. Median income for a family of
four in 1948 was $3,468. With a $2,400 exemption and $347 standard
deduction, only $721 was taxable (if they didn't itemize) -- just 20
percent of income was subject to tax. In 2001 that family earned
$63,278 and, after $11,600 of exemptions and a $7,600 standard
deduction, $44,078 was taxable -- 70 percent subject to tax. Today's
tax reaches income levels far below those deemed fair or efficient
under Roosevelt or Truman, and we're taxing a huge chunk of it for
relatively little revenue!
10
The Government Accountability Office singles out fraudulent EITC as
a "high-risk" area. The IRS estimates that deliberate and inadvertent
EITC noncompliance cost between $8.5 billion and $9.9 billion in 1999.
11
As soon as an EITC-eligible individual gets his W-2 "refund ticket," he
rushes to the tax preparer and the IRS receives a return in January.
W-2s needn't be filed with the Social Security Administration (SSA)
until February 28 (March 31 if filed electronically) and a 30-day
extension is available. There is some further delay as the SSA
processes and finally shares the information with the IRS. Except when
security procedures have stopped a refund from being issued, it's only
long after refunds have been cashed that the IRS can begin determining
whether EITC refunds were proper. Protecting against fraudulent EITC
diverts tremendous IRS resources that could quite profitably be
directed toward high-income taxpayer compliance.
The EITC has fueled the growth of the commercial tax preparation
industry. Few low-wage earners take advantage of the EITC advance
payment process (Form W-5), so most have a large refund due at year-
end. They are often in desperate need of money, and commercial
preparers have developed sophisticated marketing presentations to sell
those taxpayers refund anticipation loans with electronic filing. The
refund which arrives three weeks earlier than it otherwise would costs
those poor taxpayers 100 percent to 400 percent per annum interest.
The EITC and the child credit turn a simple tax return into one
that is very complex. Unintelligible statutes force people to seek
professional help. Can anyone translate or justify the following
gobbledygook:
The amount of the credit allowed under this subsection shall not be
treated as a credit allowed under this subpart and shall reduce the
amount of credit otherwise allowable under subsection (a) without
regard to section 26(a). [IRC section 24(d)(1), child tax credit.]
Any wonder that the tax preparation industry pockets more than 10
percent of the EITC program on returns it prepares,
12
probably the largest overhead for any federal welfare program? The fee
abuses by the industry continue to be prosecuted by state attorneys
general. Jackson Hewitt, the nation's second-largest preparer,
reportedly earned 29 percent of its net revenues from facilitating tax
refund loans.
13
Some praise the Tax Reform Act of 1986 (TRA 86) as the model for a
broad-based, revenue-neutral, low rate, efficient, and equitable tax
system. As a tax return preparer, I found that it brought horrible
complexity by dividing income into baskets of active income, passive
income, and portfolio income. It introduced new discrepancies between
book income and taxable income, and additional categories of
alternative minimum taxable income. It added complex phaseouts of the
benefit of the 15 percent bracket, itemized deductions, and personal
exemptions. As it eliminated garden-variety real estate tax shelters,
it added low-income housing credits, bringing a whole new generation of
tax shelter promotion.
The real simplification in TRA 86 was elimination of preferential
tax treatment for capital gains. But Congress was so confident that the
repeal would be temporary that it failed to repeal the code sections
distinguishing between long-term and short-term capital gains. The IRS
was also skeptical and retained separate sections on Schedule D for
tracking long-term and short-term capital transactions.
Regressivity
While tax rates have risen from the 28 percent TRA 86 rate, capital
gains and dividend rates have been halved. The result is that some
investment income is now taxed at a maximum 15 percent rate. Never
before has this nation inverted taxation to favor the wealthy
investment class over the working middle class. Even Richard Nixon gave
a preference to wages with a maximum rate of 50 percent while other
income was taxed at 70 percent.
In Bryan's time, tariffs made taxation regressive. Today it's
Social Security taxes. The intergenerational promise of Social Security
is financed through a tax on wage income under $90,000. Benefits are
skewed so that those earning at the higher end toward $90,000 finance
those earning at the lower end toward $3,000.
Fairness requires a review of the regressivity of FICA and self-
employment taxes when considered in combination with the income tax.
FICA began as a 2 percent levy. Today, it's a combined 15.3 percent on
employees and employers. The government calculates a "reserve fund,"
the difference between cumulative receipts and benefits, but the
reserve is used for current government spending. The mythical "reserve"
cannot hide the regressive nature of a payroll tax whose surplus makes
the federal budget deficit look much smaller.
A self-employed family that struggles to maintain a lower-
middle-class lifestyle on $40,000 of income may owe no income tax, but
pays nearly $6,000 in self-employment tax. For most people, the 15.3
percent burden on earned income far exceeds their income tax. What
logic justifies a combined 30.3 percent marginal tax rate on those
earning up to $60,000 annually, while higher incomes are taxed at a
maximum of 35 percent, or 15 percent when income consists of capital
gains and dividends? From a rate perspective, our tax on income has
become regressive.
14
Tax Fairness
Randolph Paul asserted that fairness in U.S. income taxation has been
designed around ability to pay and rate progressivity. Conscious design
should take advantage of the fact that lower-income individuals spend
almost all of their income on consumption while higher-income
individuals are the source for most savings and investment. That
dichotomy between the consuming and saving segments provides an
opportunity to simplify the income tax.
A consumption tax will reach all lower-income earnings, while an
income tax is the only tax that will reach higher-income earnings. We
don't need an income tax, certainly not a complex one, to tax the
majority with lower incomes. Bryan's "insignia of freemen" alluded to
consumption taxes in the form of tariffs and excises.
To collect $72 billion from the lower 68 percent, there are
alternatives that don't require a tax return. How much is $72 billion?
It's an 8 percent flat income withholding tax at source on the 68
percent. Or it's the equivalent of raising tax rates on the 32 percent
by just 2 percent, but not as simple as exempting the first $60,000 of
income. That 32 percent also pays tax on income below $60,000. I'm not
advocating any particular method. Rather, I am merely demonstrating
that a replacement for $72 billion in revenue is easily within reach.
15
Rep. John Linder, R-Ga., has proposed a regressive tax insidiously
called the FairTax. It's a 23 percent flat federal sales tax that would
replace income and Social Security taxes. The practical effect would
dramatically lower the tax on the wealthy and raise it on the poor and
middle classes. The simple fact is that the majority spends everything
they earn and would be fully taxed, while the wealthy could avoid the
tax by saving, or spending abroad.
16
Michael Graetz proposes a new federal value added tax at a 10
percent to 15 percent rate, a $100,000 family income tax exemption
($50,000 single), and a 25 percent income tax for those above the
$100,000 threshold. He claims that his proposal would reduce tax return
filings by 80 percent to 90 percent. Failing that, Graetz proposes
repeal of the regular tax because by 2008, the AMT will produce more
revenue than the regular tax while requiring filing of 40 million fewer
tax returns. That would bring far more simplification and fairness than
the Linder tax and introduce a major new revenue source. It might also
be an invitation to a far higher tax burden that could more simply be
generated through the existing income tax mechanism.
17
The income tax is one of the most flexible and useful taxes. It can
be used as a weapon against inflation or to redistribute wealth.
Adjusting rates and the taxable base at the high end influences savings
and investment. Those same adjustments at the low end influence
consumption. It has been overused to effect social and economic
policies, another proof of its utility. No other single tax serves so
many functions.
The revenue stream from the income tax is sufficiently reliable,
without inducing inflation, to leverage debt. It was the revenue stream
from income taxes that enabled the United States to finance the Civil
War, World War I, and World War II, and convinced lenders that our
government was creditworthy so that it could borrow many times the tax
base. That still holds true today.
The Challenge
There will be fierce opposition to reducing participation in the income
tax. Many will promote the old argument of William Bourke Cockran that
the poor must participate in every tax the government imposes or lose
the right of participation. The tax preparation industry will oppose,
arguing that the current system works. (No, it's broken. That's why we
have a tax reform commission.) The real estate industry will predict a
collapse. Charities will predict a humanitarian disaster. Insurance
companies are already squawking that they might lose half their
products without tax incentives. A friend at the IRS volunteer income
tax assistance program argued with me that the poor shouldn't be
deprived of participation in the income tax.
The wealthy will oppose being singled out for income tax. The poor
will fear loss of the EITC (even if unfounded). Most arguments will be
speculative. Congress will fear loss of influence as the majority of
the population loses immediate concern for an income tax that no longer
reaches them. (Not to mention the effect on campaign fundraising.)
The benefits from concentrating on just the 32 percent of the
population that yields the substantial revenue on which our nation
depends includes reduced compliance costs. That would save consumers
and businesses billions of dollars annually. Much complexity stems from
arranging fairness for the majority 68 percent. Reducing income tax
filings by 89 million would vastly simplify the IRS computer
modernization program, the second high-risk area identified by the GAO.
We could simplify tax calculations. It has become increasingly
difficult to manually verify a computer tax calculation. There are
three interacting baskets of income: (1) regular income tax at 10
percent, 15 percent, 25 percent, 28 percent, 33 percent, and 35
percent, (2) alternative minimum income tax at 26 percent and 28
percent, and (3) capital gains tax at 5 percent, 15 percent, 25
percent, and 28 percent on net long-term capital gains in excess of net
short-term capital losses, interacting with the ordinary rates and the
AMT, plus all the phaseouts. Those calculations precede the tax credits
and additional taxes that must also be computed to arrive at the proper
tax liability.
Twenty-five years ago I would review returns for missed deductions
or elections or failure to use income averaging. Today the big errors
are often buried in complex computer calculations of AMT adjustments
that few preparers manually verify. Those errors are as likely to favor
the government as the taxpayer.
In making its individual income tax recommendations, the tax reform
commission should (1) drop the filing requirement for tens of millions
of unnecessary tax returns, (2) reduce and restrict the nonrevenue
functions of the IRS, (3) rationalize the tax burden we place on the
spending class and the incentives we provide to the saving class, and
(4) improve progressivity of our tax structure.
Graetz correctly points out that "[t]he fundamental problem is that
the IRS is being asked to do too much." Getting the IRS to do less
involves dramatically reducing the number of tax returns that are
filed. The tax reform commission will fail if it does not get rid of
unnecessary returns by whatever means it decides to propose.
Simplifying taxes is easy. Just get rid of 89 million unnecessary
income tax returns.
FOOTNOTES
1 Randolph E. Paul,
Taxation for Prosperity
(Indianapolis: Bobs-Merrill Company, 1947), p. 261. Paul was a
prominent tax lawyer, founder of Paul, Weiss, Rifkind, Wharton, and
Garrison, and author of many tax books, including coauthoring the
original
Mertens Law of Federal Income Taxation. He was
Treasury general counsel during World War II and was the one who turned
the income tax into a mass tax.
See http://www.taxhistory.org/thp/readings.nsf/
.
2 Michael Graetz, "100 Million Unnecessary Returns: A
Fresh Start for the U.S. Tax System," 112
Yale Law Journal 261
(November 2002).
3 Scott Hodge, "44 Million Will File Tax Returns But
Pay Nothing," Tax Foundation's
Tax Features, March/April 2004,
p. 1. Updated article at
http://www.taxfoundation.org/publications/show/542.html.
4 William Bourke Cockran. 53-2 Cong. Rec. vol. 26,
Appendix, pp. 462-469 (Jan. 30, 1894) at 464-465.
5 William Jennings Bryan. 53-2 Cong. Rec. vol. 26, pp.
1655-1658 (Jan. 30, 1894) at 1656.
6 Jordan A. Schwarz, "John Nance Garner and the Sales
Tax Rebellion of 1932,"
Journal of Southern History, May 1964,
pp. 162-180. Garner's poor handling of the sales tax issue is one
reason Roosevelt defeated him for the 1932 Democratic presidential
nomination. Garner had to settle for vice president.
7 Randolph Paul,
Taxation in the United States
(Boston: Little, Brown, and Company, 1954), pp. 326-349. Paul wrote
that a comprehensive study on a federal retail sales tax was inserted
into the printed record of the Ways and Means Committee hearings in
July 1943. I have not checked the
Congressional Record, but the
following memo may be the study he was referring to: "Considerations
Respecting a Federal Retail Sales Tax," Staff Memo, Division of Tax
Research, U.S. Treasury Department, Aug. 26, 1943, reproduced at
http://www.taxhistory.org/Civilization/Documents/
Sales/HST29010/sales.htm.
8 Paul,
supra note 1, at 149-154, 186.
9 John F. Witte,
The Politics and Development of
the Federal Income Tax (Madison, WI: University of Wisconsin Press,
1985), pp. 147-148.
10 U.S. Census Bureau, "Historical Income Tables --
Table F-8. Size of Family by Median and Mean Income: 1947 to 2001,
Families With Four People,"
see http://www.census.gov/hhes/income/histinc/f08.html.
11 "High-Risk Series, an Update," U.S. Government
Accountability Office, GAO-05-207 (January 2005), pp. 37- 38; "Internal
Revenue Service, Recommendations to Improve Financial Operational
Management," U.S. General Accounting Office, GAO-01-42 (November 2000);
"Internal Revenue Service, Status of Recommendations From Financial
Audits and Related Financial Management Reports," U.S. Government
Accountability Office, GAO- 05-393 (April 2005), p. 21.
12 Janet Spragens and Nancy Abramowitz, "Low-Income
Taxpayers and the Modernized IRS: A View From the Trenches,"
Tax
Notes, June 13, 2005, p. 1407; Alan Berube, Anne Kim, Benjamin
Forman, and Megan Burns, "The Price of Paying Taxes: How Tax
Preparation and Refund Loan Fees Erode the Benefits of the EITC," the
Brookings Institution and Progressive Policy Institute Survey Series
(May 2002);
see "Low Income Taxpayer Protection Act of 2005,"
H.R. 894 (2005), section 4(a)(1)(B), or search at
http://thomas.loc.gov.
13 "Tax Loans: Quick Cash, Steep Price,"
Atlanta
Journal-Constitution, April 3, 2005, p. D1; David Cay Johnston,
"Tax Credit Is Financial Bonanza for 2 Big Tax Preparers,"
New York
Times, May 21, 2002, p. C1.
14 EITC and other welfare programs offset much
regressivity for low-income taxpayers. For a full discussion of this
complex subject, see C. Eugene Steuerle and Jon M. Bakija,
Retooling
Social Security for the 21st Century, Right & Wrong Approaches to
Reform (Washington, D.C.: Urban Institute Press, 1994).
15 Taxable income in 2002 totaled $4.1 trillion.
Replacing $72 billion lost from exempting almost $900 billion of
taxable income of the 68 percent majority requires raising rates on the
32 percent that remain by just 2 percent. The same $72 billion could be
raised with an 8 percent flat withholding tax on lower incomes.
16 Linder has coauthored
The Fair Tax Book: Saying
Goodbye to the Income Tax and the IRS, with radio talk show host
Neal Boortz. Though he wrote this book on tax policy, Boortz seems
never to have heard of Tax Analysts before reading that he's been
awarded "this year's prize for Worst Idea in a Serious Public Policy
Debate." This ignorant tax book is a bestseller.
http://www.taxhistory.org, click
on "Readings in Tax History," then "Fair Tax, Bad Tax" (May 26, 2005).
17 Graetz,
supra note 2. Sheryl Stratton, "Tax
Lawyers Critique Graetz Reform Plan at Judicial Conference,"
Tax
Notes, May 2, 2005, p. 560.
END OF FOOTNOTES
Jay Starkman is a sole practitioner in Atlanta. This article was originally published in Tax Notes, August 15, 2005. (c)2005 Tax Analysts.
Created: August 23, 2005; Last updated: March 12, 2009